Random Walk Theory and the Romanian Capital Market A New Perspective

Ana Maria Calomfir (Metescu), Cristian Silviu Bănacu and Doina I. Popescu

The Bucharest University of Economic Studies, Bucharest, Romania.

Copyright © 2012 Ana Maria Calomfir (Metescu), Cristian Silviu Bănacu and Doina I. Popescu. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License unported 3.0, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided that original work is properly cited.

Abstract

Forecasting rates of return, thus the attempt to predict the behavior of financial assets, with an increased degree of accuracy, represents one of the most outstanding challenges for the academic and investment area. The main purpose of the paper is to analyze past fluctuations of the prices of security titles, taking into account the original hypothesis that they are influenced by past values of those prices, and of course, taking into consideration the fact that the amount of data an investor may posses is much richer than the amount of historical data, with respect to the rates of return time series. In the end , some conclusions regarding the application of the random walk theory and the Romanian capital market efficiency were drawn, based on the results obtained from the statistical tests, and also, due to the fact that the market efficiency has, as a theoretical approach and mathematical model, the random walk theory.

Keywords: random walk, market efficiency, information, capital markets.

Introduction

In 1827 an English botanist, Robert Brown, noticed that small particles suspended in fluids perform peculiarly erratic movements. This phenomenon, which could also be attributed to gases, is referred to as Brownian motion. After that moment further, the theory has been considerably generalized and exteded by Fokker, Planck, Burger, Ornstein, Uhlenbeck, Chandrasekhar, Kramers and others. On the purely mathematical side, various aspects of the theory were analysed by Wiener, Kolmogoroff, Feller, Levy, Doob (1939) and Fortet (1943). Even Albert Einstein had an important contribution to this theory.

The limitations of this theory were already recognized by Einstein and Smoluchowski (1916), but are often disregarded by other writers. An improved theory, known as „exact”, was advanced by Uhlenbeck and Ornstein (the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Process) (1930) and by Kramers (1946). The random walk theory was first brought to light by the discrete approach of Einstein-Smoluchowski, and it consists in treating Brownian motion as a discrete random walk. The main advantages of this discrete approach are pedagogical, but it may suggest various generalizations which will contribute to the development of the Calculus of Probability.

The random walk theory has nowadays a practical implication into the financial theory, stating that the stock prices evolve accordingly to a random walk, and thus they are impossible to predict. This theory is consistent with the efficient-market hypothesis. In finance, this theory is mainly linked by the name of Eugene Fama (1965), even if Burton Malkiel (1973) is considered to have strongly developed it.

Methodology

The study was conducting by starting with reviewing the literature regarding the Brownian motion, Wiener process, Ito process, Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process and reaching the random walk theory. Starting from the major theories, the random walk theory is presented under its major sub-hypothesis, starting from independent and identically distributed increments and reaching to dependent increments, but uncorrelated. In order to apply those hypothesis, there were used time series extracted from the daily closing prices for the Company of Financial Investment Services (SIF5), for the period starting from the 5th of January, 2009, and ending to the 14th of February, 2012. All the three sub-hypothesis of the random walk theory are tested using different statistical tests, in order to determine the application and the compliance of this theory with the Romanian Stock Market.

Random Walk Theory – Major Sub-Hypothesis

Basically, a market is defined to be information – efficient if no investors can reach abnormal systematic earnings and, also, the true expected return of any security is equal to its equilibrum expected value (Fama, 1976). From the first point of view, the main concern for the market is to give equal chances to each investor, which means that there are no investors able to gain every time and investors to lose every time. From the second opinion, it is important for markets to work, thing that will have as a result a right estimation of asset returns. In this context, there were many trials to develop instruments for testing market information efficiency. Many investigation techniques used in order to test the possibility of earning abnormal returns were revealed. In this sense, Kendall (1956) and Alexander (1961) turned to tests of the serial correlation; Fama and Blume (1966) appealed to simple trading rules tests; Jagadeesh (1990) and Jagadeesh and Titman (1993) resorted to overreaction tests; DeBondt and Thaler (1985), Poterba and Summers (1998) and Fama and French (1988) fell back upon tests of long-horizon return predictability.

Campbell, Lo and MacKinley (1997) stated that „any test of efficiency must assume an equilibrum model that defines normal security returns. If efficient hypothesis is rejected, this can be because the market is truly inefficient or because an incorrect equilibrum model has been assumed”.

Fama (1970) stated that a market is information efficient if prices fully reflect all the available information from the market.

The notion of market efficiency can be as follows: the more efficient the market is, the more aleatory the sequence of price changes generated by the market is (Dragota, Stoian, Pele, Mitrica, Bensafta, 2009).

At least with the emerging markets, such as East European Ex-communist Countries, due to some of their particular features, such as lack of liquidity, econometric tests could be distorted (Pele and Voineagu, 2008). The informational efficiency of the Romanian capital market was differently tested in the past years. From this point of view, most of the studies were related to the possibility of gaining abnormal earnings (Dragota, Caruntu, Stoian, 2006).

Similar studies were done for other ex-communist countries. For instance, Chun (2000) based on variance ratio tests found that the Hungarian capital market was weakly efficient; Gilmore and McManus (2003) investigated informational efficiency in its weak form from the Czech Republic, Poland and Hungary (within 1995-2000) and rejected the random walk hypothesis based on the results of a model comparison approach.

Consequently, the statistical manner to express the market efficiency is the random walk hypothesis (RWH), which can be formulated in three different sub-hypothesis, respectively: independently and identically distributed increments, independent increments, and uncorrelated increments. Those sub-hypothesis start from a less broad perspective, getting to a more relaxed and natural perspective. Those hypothesis are further presented:

RW1 Hypothesis: Independent Increments, Identically Distributed

The most natural way of expressing the random walk hypothesis is the one in which the price of financial assets is represented by a stochastic process, following an internal dependency of the manner:

Pt = μ + Pt-1 + εt                                                                                                     (1)

Where εt WN (0,σ2) represents a white noise, a series of independent random variables, identically distributed:

E t] = 0,∀t
Var t] = σ2,∀t
εt si εt+k  sunt variabile independente,∀k ≠ 0

More, covtt+k] = 0 and cov t2t2+k] = 0,∀k ≠ 0.

In equation (1), Pt, Pt-1 represent the price values for two successive time moments, and μ represents the expected price movement, the so-called drift.

The most common condition for the random variable εt is the fact it follows a normal distribution function, except the fact that it represents a white noise, condition that generates a certain formal commonness. But this may be the cause of appearing certain irregularities with the practice, due to the fact that the normal distribution function covers the whole range of real numbers, and it may result into the fact that there may be a non-zero probability that the price of a security title to be negative. A way of avoiding this fact may be by using instead of stock prices series, the series of  natural logarithms of those prices: pt = log⁡ Pt.

Model RW becomes then a log-normal model:

pt = μ + pt-1+εt                                                                                                       (2)

Where εt WN (0,σ2) represents a white noise.

RW2 Hypothesis: Independent Increments

Even the simplicity and the elegance of the RW1 Model seem very alluring, the supposition of the existence of identically distributed independent increments is not quite natural. 

The influencing factors that determine the evolution of the prices of financial assets are not always the same and do not affect those prices with the same intensity. Also, the economic conditions vary much during time, this making the hypothesis of the existence of the same distribution function over time to be not natural.

Then, the RW2 model derives directly from the RW1 model, but the single difference resides in ignoring the hypothesis of the same distribution function of the random variable εt:

Pt = μ + Pt-1+ εt, where εt is a series of random variables:

E [εt] = 0,∀t
Var [εt] = σt2,∀t
cov [εtt+k] = 0 and cov [εt2,εt2+k] = 0,∀k ≠ 0.

Even RW2 model is weaker than the RW1 model, the former keeps the essence of the latter: every future movement of the stock prices is unpredictable, using the past price movements.

RW3 Hypothesis: Uncorrelated Increments

Relaxing the hypothesis of the above-described models, we can obtain a more generalized form of the random walk hypothesis, in which increments are dependent, but uncorrelated.

Pt = μ + Pt-1 + εt, where εt is a series of random variables:

E [εt] = 0,∀t
Var [εt] = σt2,∀t
cov [εtt+k] = 0

In order to test the RW1 hypothesis, it was used the Runs Test, while for testing the RW3 hypothesis, one of the most natural ways was to detect some possible serial correlations, correlations existent between the values of a time series in different moments in time.

Following the conditions of the weakest random walk hypothesis, RW3, first order differences are uncorrelated for every time interval; as a consequence, for testing the RW3 hypothesis, we will observe the values the autocorrelation coefficient takes in different time moments. A powerful test, that may detect the evidence of the RW1 hypothesis, is produced by the Q-Statistics, introduced by Box and Pierce (1970). Ljung and Box (1978) have offered an alternative to this test, for small-size samples.

An important property of all random walk hypothesis is the fact that the variance of the residuals must be a function varying linearly with respect to time. As a consequence of this fact, the random walk hypothesis may be tested with the variances’ ratio (Multiple Variance ratio Test). In order to make a decision regarding the acceptance or the rejection of the random walk hypothesis, the Multiple Variance Ratio (MVR) approach was used (Chow and Denning, 1993).

In order to test different aspects regarding the behavior of financial assets, we have used daily closing prices for the Company of Financial Investment Services (SIF5), for the period starting from the 5th of January, 2009, and ending to the 14th of February, 2012. Based on those data, we have computed the daily rates of return, using the every day closing prices, by the formula:  , where  Pt  represents the daily closing price of day t.

Descriptive Statistics and Verifying the Normal Distribution of the Daily Rates of Return

Analyzing the indicators of the daily returns distribution, we can draw the following conclusions:

  • In all the cases, the Gaussian distribution hypothesis cannot be accepted, due to both the values of the kurtosis coefficient, and to the values of the Jarque-Berra Statistics.
  • The distribution of the returns is leptokurtic, different form the shape of a standard normal distribution.
 

In order to verify the random walk hypothesis for the daily rates of return for the Company SIF 5, we have applied the Runns Test in SPSS and the Multiple Variance Ratio Test in Eviews, in both cases with or without homoskedasticity.

Table 1. Random Walk Hypothesis for Daily Rates of Return of the Company SIF5

 

The value Asymp.Sig(2-tailed) (superior to the level of 5%) corresponding to the z test for the cutting point does not put into evidence the rejection of the null hypothesis, according to which the daily rates of return follow a random walk process, that may conduct to the conclusion that, indeed, these daily rates of return follow a random walk movement, according to the results obtained from the Runns test.

Table 2. Multiple Variance Ratio Test for the RW1 hypothesis
(With the Supposition that the Homoskedasticity Condition is being Fulfilled)
 
 

 

The Chow-Denning Statistics of 3.32 is associated to the period 16 of the individual tests. P-value probability of 0.0035 conducts to rejecting the null hypothesis of random walk. The results are similar also for the Wald Test for the common hypothesis. The individual statistics conduct to the rejection of the null hypothesis, the p-value probability being inferior to the level of 0.05.

Table 3. Multiple Variance Ratio Test for the RW3 Hypothesis
(Supposing that the Heteroskedasticity Condition is being Fulfilled)

 

 

Probabilities p-value of the individual tests, which have been generated using the wild bootstrap technique are in general consistent with the previous results, even if they are relatively higher than before. The individual test for the period 2, which was significant in the case of homoskedasticity, becomes insignificant for a significance level of 5%. The result of the Chow-Denning Test is 2.72 with a p-value probability of 0.02, which may conduct to the rejection of the null hypothesis that log close is a martingale.

Conclusions

After performing and running the statistical tests, some major conclusions may be drawn:

  • The Runs Test, even if it has a limitative explanatory power, conducts to the general acceptance of the random walk hypothesis of the daily closing price of the stock share of company SIF5;
  • The Multiple Variance Ratio Test conducts to the rejection of the RW1 hypothesis, supposing that the homoskedasticity condition is being fulfilled;
  • The Multiple Variance Ration Test conducts to the rejection of the RW3 hypothesis, supposing that heteroskedasticity condition is being fulfilled.

Based on the results discussed above, it is difficult to state if the Romanian capital market is informational efficient in its weak form.

These results sustain the hypothesis that the Romanian capital market improved its performance over the last few years. Also, the Romanian investors’ professional experience increased, and probably, their ability to evaluate assets in an appropriate manner has developed. All these conclusions revealed from the study related the fair game on the Romanian capital market, which is in accordance with Pele and Voineagu (2008) conclusions.

Acknowledgments

This article is a result of the project POSDRU/88/1.5./S/55287 „Doctoral Programme in Economics at European Knowledge Standards (DOESEC)”. This project is co-funded by the European Social Fund through The Sectorial Operational Programme for Human Resources Development 2007-2013, coordinated by The Bucharest Academy of Economic Studies in partnership with West University of Timisoara.

(adsbygoogle = window.adsbygoogle || []).push({});

References

Alexander, S. S. (1961). “Price Movements in Speculative Markets. Trends or Random Walks,” Industrial Management Review 2(7), 26.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Box, G. E. P. & Jenkins, G. M. (1970). ‘Time Series Analysis. Forecasting and Control,’ HoldenDay, San Francisco.
Google Scholar

Burton G. Malkiel Session Chairman & Fama, E. F. (1970). “Efficient Capital Market: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work,” Journal of Finance, 25, 383-417.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Campbell, J. Y., Lo, A. W. & MacKinley, A. C. (1997). ‘The Econometrics of Finanacial Markets,’ Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Chow, V. K. & Denning, K. C. (1993). “A Simple Multiple Variance Ratio Test,” Journal of Econometrics, 58, 385-401.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Chun, R. M. (2000). “Compensation Vouchers and Equity Markets: Evidence from Hungary,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 24, 1155-1178.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

De Bondt, W. F. M. & Thaler, R. (1985). “Does the Stock Market Overreact?,” Journal of Finance, 40, 793-805.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Dragota, V., Caruntu, M. & Stoian, A. (2006). “Market Informational Efficiency and Investors’ Rationality: Some Evidences on Romanian Capital Market,” CERGE Foundation Project, [Online], [Retrieved March 22, 2012],
https://iweb.cerge-ei.cz/pdf/gdn/RRCV_19_paper_03.pdf
Publisher 

Dragota, V., Stoian, A., Pele, D. T., Mitrica, E. & Bensafta, M. (2009). “The Development of the Romanian Capital Market: Evidences on Information Efficiency,” Romanian Journal for Economic Forecasting, 6(2), 147-160.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Fama, E. F. (1965). “Random Walks in Stock Market Prices,” Financial Analysts Journal 21(5), 55-59.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Fama, E. F. & Blume, M. E. (1966). “Filter Rules and Stock –Market Trading,” Journal of Business, 39, 226-241.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Gilmore, C. & McManus, G. M. (2003). “Random Walk and Efficiency Tests of Central European Equity Markets,” Managerial Finance, 29, 42-61.
PublisherGoogle Scholar – British Library Direct

Jegadeesh, N. (1990). “Evidence of Predictable Behavior of Security Returns,” Journal of Finance, 45, 881-898.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Jegadeesh, N. & Titman, S. (1993). “Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency,” Journal of Finance, 48, 65-91.
PublisherGoogle Scholar – British Library Direct

Kac, M. (1947). “Random Walk and the Theory of Brownian Motion,” The American Mathematical Monthly 54(7), 369-391, Published by: Mathematical Association of America.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Kendall, M. G. (1953). “The Analysis of Economic Time Series, Part I: Prices,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 96, 11-25.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Lo, A. W. & MacKinley, A. C. (1988). “Stock Market Prices Do Not Follow Random Walks. Evidence from a Simple Specification Test,” The Review of Financial Studies, 1, 41-66.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Pele, D. T. & Voineagu, V. (2008). “Testing Market Efficiency via Decomposition of Stock Returns. Application to Romanian Capital Market,” Romanian Journal for Economic Forecasting, 5(3), 63-79.
Publisher

Uhlenbeck, G. E. & Ornstein, L. S. (1930). “On the Theory of Brownian Motion,” Phys. Rev. 36, 823-841.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Wang, M. C. & Uhlenbeck, G. E. (1945). “On the theory of Brownian Motion,” Rev. Mod. Phys. 17, 323-342.
PublisherGoogle Scholar

Shares